Home
Work in progress
News

Workshops
References (project)
Current References (general)
Project


CNAM
LATAPSES
EHESS
ENST

Cooperation, reciprocity and community governance

 


Cooperation and reciprocity

 

  • Professor Avner Ben-Ner, Industrial Relations Center, University of Minnesota, Minneapolis, Minnesota 55455
  • Professor Louis Putterman, Department of Economics, Box B, Brown University, Providence, RI 02912

Ben-Ner Avner, Putterman Louis [1998], Economics, Values, and Organization, Cambridge University Press, March 1998.

  • Table of Contents
  • Avner Ben-Ner and Louis Putterman, Values and Institutions in Economic Analysis
  • Part I. The Formation and Evolution of Social Norms and Values
  • Robert Sugden, The Simultaneous Evolution of Institutions and Norms
  • Ken Binmore, A Utilitarian Theory of Political Legitimacy
  • Chaim Fershtman and Yoram Weiss, Why Do We Care What Others Think About Us?
  • Jane Mansbridge, Starting with Nothing: On the Impossibility of Grounding Norms Solely in Self-Interest
  • Part II. The Generation and Transmission of Values in Families and Communities
  • Nancy Folbre and Tom Weisskopf, Did Father Know Best? Families, Markets, and the Supply of Caring Labor
  • Samuel Bowles and Herbert Gintis, How Communities Govern: The Structural Basis of Pro-Social Norms
  • Timur Kuran, The Limits of Moral Diversity
  • John Michael Montias, Moral Diversity and Specialized Values: Some Observations
  • Part III. Social Norms and Culture
  • Robert Frank, Social Norms as Positional Arms Control Agreements
  • Susan Rose-Ackerman, Gifts and Bribes
  • Viviana Zelizer, How Do We Know Whether a Monetary Transaction is a Gift, an Entitlement, or a Payment?
  • Part IV. The Organization of Work, Trust, and Incentives
  • Ernst Fehr and Simon Gachter, How Effective Are Trust- and Reciprocity-Based Incentives?
  • Andrew Schotter, Worker Trust, System Vulnerability, and the Performance of Work Groups
  • Jonathan Baron, Trust: Beliefs and Morality
  • Russell Hardin, Who is the Custodian of the Custodians?
  • Part V. Markets, Values, and Welfare
  • Bruno S. Frey, Institutions and Morale: The Crowding-Out Effect
  • Robert Lane, The Joyless Market Economy
  • Epilogue
  • Douglass North, Where Have We Been and Where Are We Going?

Ben-Ner A., Putterman L. [1999], Reciprocity in a Two Part Dictator Game, Working Paper, http://econ.pstc.brown.edu/faculty/putterman/working/working.html

Reciprocity is a widely observed phenomenon for which evolutionary foundations are posited. We conduct a dictator game in which recipients in an initial game become dictators in a second game. The amount sent by those sending back to the person from whom they received some or no dollars is strongly correlated with the amount received by them, although the interaction is one time and zero sum in nature. No such correlation between amounts sent and received is exhibited when second round dictators are instead paired with new partners. Intelligence and personality test results, gender, and other characteristics also help to predict sending behavior. (JEL C91, A13, D00)

Falk, Armin and Urs Fischbacher, [1998], "A Theoy of Reciprocity", Working Paper, University of Zurich.

Falk, Armin, Ernst Fehr, Urs Fischbacher [2001], "Driving Forces of Informal Sanctions", Working Paper, http://www.iew.unizh.ch/home/falk/

Informal sanctions are a major determinant of a society’s social capital because they are key to the enforcement of implicit agreements and social norms. Yet, little is known about the driving forces behind informal sanctions. We systematically examine the determinants of informal sanctions by a large number of experiments. Our experiments allow us to identify the relative importance of three major potential factors: (i) strategic sanctioning for selfish reasons, (ii) non-strategic sanctions driven by spitefulness, and (iii) non-strategic sanctions that are driven by the violation of fairness principles. In addition, the observed sanctioning patterns provide insights into the relevance of different fairness principles. Our findings show that the violation of fairness principles is the most important driving force of sanctions but, in addition, a non-negligible part of the sanctions is driven by spitefulness. We find surprisingly little evidence for strategic sanctions that are imposed to create future material benefits. While non-strategic sanctions are of major importance in our experiments, strategic sanctions seem to play a negligible role. Within the class of fairnessdriven sanctions the motive to harm those who committed unfair actions seems most important. Keywords: Informal Sanction, Social Norm, Social Capital, Strategic Sanction, Fairness, Reciprocity, Spitefulness. JEL classification: A13, D63, D23, C92, K42

 

Falk, Armin, Ernst Fehr, Urs Fischbacher [2000], Testing Theories of Fairness - Intentions Matter, working paper, http://www.iew.unizh.ch/home/falk/

Recently developed models of fairness can explain a wide variety of seemingly contradictory facts. The most controversial and yet unresolved issue in the modeling of fairness preferences concerns the behavioral relevance of fairness intentions. Intuitively, fairness intentions seem to play an important role in economic relations, political struggles and legal disputes. Yet, so far there is little rigorous evidence supporting this intuition. In this paper we provide clear and unambiguous experimental evidence for the behavioral relevance of fairness intentions. Our results indicate that the attribution of fairness intentions is important both in the domain of negatively reciprocal behavior and in the domain of positively reciprocal behavior. This means that reciprocal behavior cannot be fully captured by equity models that are exclusively based on preferences over the distribution of material payoffs. Models that take into account players’ fairness intentions and distributional preferences are consistent with our data while models that focus exclusively on intentions or on the distribution of material payoffs are not. JEL-Classification: D63, C78, C91. Keywords: Fairness, reciprocity, intentions, experiments, moonlighting game.

Fehr Ernst, Schmidt K. [2001], "Theories of Fairness and Reciprocity - Evidence and Economic Applications", forthcoming in: M. Dewatripont, L. Hansen and St. Turnovsky (Eds.), Advances in Economics and Econometrics - 8th World Congress, Econometric Society Monographs. (with K. Schmidt), http://www.iew.unizh.ch/home/fehr/

Most economic models are based on the self interest hypothesis that assumes that all people are exclusively motivated by their material self-interest. In recent years experimental economists have gathered overwhelming evidence that systematically refutes the self-interest hypothesis and suggests that many people are strongly motivated by concerns for fairness and reciprocity. Moreover, several theoretical papers have been written showing that the observed phenomena can be explained in a rigorous and tractable manner. These theories in turn induced a new wave of experimental research offering additional exciting insights into the nature of preferences and into the relative performance of competing theories of fairness. The purpose of this paper is to review these recent developments, to point out open questions, and to suggest avenues for future research.

Fehr E., Gächter S. [1997], "Reciprocity as a Contract Enforcement Device: Experimental Evidence", Econometrica 65,4 (July), p.833-860.

 

Joel Guttman

Guttman J. [2000], "On the Evolutionary stability of preferences for reciprocity", European Journal of Political Economy, 16, p.31-50.

 

Forsythe, Robert, Joel L. Horowitz, N.E. Savin and Martin Sefton, [1994], “Fairness in Simple Bargaining Experiments”, Games and Economic Behavior 6: 347-69.

Clark Kenneth, Martin Sefton [2001], "The Sequential Prisoner's Dilemma: Evidence on Reciprocation", Economic Journal 111, 51-68.

http://www.nottingham.ac.uk/economics/cedex/papers/spd.htm

We investigate how fairness concerns influence individual behaviour in social dilemmas. Using a Sequential Prisoner's Dilemma experiment we analyse the extent to which cooperation is conditional on first-mover cooperation, repetition, economic incentives, subject pool (UK vs. US) and gender. We find the most important variable influencing cooperation is the first-mover's choice, supporting the argument that cooperative behaviour in social dilemmas reflects reciprocation rather than unconditional altruism. However, we also find that cooperation decreases with repetition, and reciprocation falls as its material cost rises. Keywords : Fairness, reciprocity, experimental economics, sequential prisoner's dilemma. JEL Classification : C72, C92.

Todd L. Cherry, Department of Economics, Appalachian State University, Boone, NC 28608-2051, USA

Cherry Todd L. [2001], "Mental accounting and other-regarding behavior: Evidence from the lab", Journal of Economic Psychology, Volume 22, Issue 5, October 2001, Pages 605-615.

This paper uncovers a key determinant of the other-regarding behavior that permeates bargaining experiments. Examining a one-shot dictator game that has the first-mover dictate the split of an amount of money, dictators acting over earned money exhibited self-interested behavior in 76% of bargains. This result stands in stark contrast to the baseline experiment in which dictators acting over allocated money displayed self-interested behavior in only 26% of bargains. Self-interested behavior appeared at greater levels using an earnings protocol than any previous variation of the dictator game. While the distinction between earned and unearned wealth is likely context specific, the earnings protocol may be an important option for future laboratory research. Specifically, the earnings protocol may provide a closer correspondence between the laboratory and individual choices over personal assets. Author Keywords: Motivation; Fairness; Experiment Psychological classification codes: 2260; 2360JEL classification codes: C7; C9

Ishaya T., Macaulay L. [1999], "The Role of Trust in Virtual Teams", Electronic Journal of Organizational Virtualness, Vol. 1 No. 1  Page: 140-157,

http://www.virtual-organization.net

  • Russell Cooper : Department of Economics, Boston University, Boston, Massachusetts
  • Douglas V. DeJong, Robert Forsythe : College of Business Administration, University of Iowa, Iowa City, Iowa
  • Thomas W. Ross : Faculty of Commerce and Business Administration, University of British Columbia, Vancouver, British Columbia, Canada

Cooper Russell, DeJong Douglas V., Forsythe Robert, Ross Thomas W. [1996], "Cooperation without Reputation: Experimental Evidence from Prisoner's Dilemma Games", Games and Economic Behavior, Vol. 12, No. 2, February 1, 1996pp. 187-218

http://www.idealibrary.com/servlet/artid/game.1996.0013

This paper investigates cooperative play in prisoner's dilemma games by designing an experiment to evaluate the ability of two leading theories of observed cooperation: reputation building and altruism. We analyze both one-shot and finitely repeated games to gauge the importance of these theories. We conclude that neither altruism nor reputation building alone can explain our observations. The reputation model is inconsistent with play in both one-shots and finitely repeated games while the model with altruism is unable to explain observed play in the finitely repeated games. Journal of Economic Literature Classification Numbers: C72, C92.

 

Macy Michael W. and Andreas Flache [2002], "Learning Dynamics in Social Dilemmas", Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, February, 2002.

http://www.people.cornell.edu/pages/mwm14/

Macy Michael W. and Robert Willer [2002], "From Factors to Actors", Annual Review of Sociology, Vol. 28, 2002.

Macy Michael W. and John Skvoretz [1998], "The Evolution of Trust and Cooperation between Strangers: A Computational Model", American Sociological Review, October, 1998.

Macy Michael W. and David Strang [2001], "'In Search of Excellence': Fads, Success Stories, and Adaptive Emulation", American Journal of Sociology, 2001.

Macy Michael W., James Kitts, and Andreas Flache [1997], "The Weakness of Strong Ties II: Collective Action Failure in a Self-Organizing Social Network", Presented at American Sociological Association, Toronto, August 11, 1997

Akiyama E., Kaneko K. [2000], Dynamical Systems Game Theory : A New Approach to the problem of Social Dilemma, Working Paper, Santa Fe Institute

The "social dilemma" is a problem inherent in forming and maintaining cooperation among selfish individuals, and is of fundamental importance in the biological and social sciences. From the viewpoint of traditional game theory, the existence of the social dilemma necessarily implies degeneration into selfish behavior as the numbers of members in a community increases, unless there exists some external power. In the real world, however, cooperation is often formed and maintained merely through mutual interactions, without the influence of an external power. To answer questions concerning appearance and maintenance of cooperative behavior in societies, we study what we call the "Lumberjacks" Dilemma (LD) game as an application of the dynamical systems (DS) game theory presented in Ref. [1], which can naturally deal with the dynamic aspects of games. Dynamical processes that lead to the formation and maintenance of cooperation, which is often observed in the real communities, are realized in our model. The mechanism underlying this formation and maintenance is explained from the DS game point of view, by analyzing the functional dependence of the attractor of the game dynamics on a parameter characterizing the strategy. It is demonstrated that norms for cooperation are formed as strategies that are manifested as specific attractors of game dynamics. The change in the stability of this cooperative behavior as the number of members increases is also discussed. Finally, the relevance of our study to cooperation seen in the real world is discussed.

http://www.santafe.edu/~eizo/Papers/index.html

 

Clark Kenneth, Stephen Kay and Martin Sefton [1997], "When Are Nash Equilibria Self-Enforcing? An Experimental Analysis", International Journal of Game Theory

http://www.nottingham.ac.uk/economics/cedex/papers/cks.htm

We investigate the effect of non-binding pre-play communication in experiments with simple two-player coordination games. We reproduce the results of other studies in which play converges to a Pareto-dominated equilibrium in the absence of communication, and communication moves outcomes in the direction of the Pareto-dominant equilibrium. However, we provide new results which show that the effectiveness of communication is sensitive to the structure of payoffs. Our results support an argument put forward by Aumann: agreements to play a Nash equilibrium are fragile when players have a strict preference over their opponent's strategy choice. We also find that informative communication does not necessarily lead to the Pareto-dominant equilibrium.

 

Varian H., Andreoni J. [1999], "Pre-Play Contracting in the Prisoners' Dilemma", Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, Vol. 96, pp. 10933–10938, September 1999, http://www.sims.berkeley.edu/~hal/people/hal/papers.html

 

Matthew O. Jackson and Simon Wilkie

Matthew O. Jackson M.O., Wilkie S., [2000], Endogenous Games and Mechanisms: Side Payments Among Players, Working Paper , September 2000

We characterize the outcomes of games when players may make binding offers of strategy-contingent side payments before the game is played. This does not always lead to efficient outcomes, despite complete information and costless contracting. The characterizations are illustrated in a series of examples, including voluntary contribution public good games, Cournot and Bertrand oligopoly, principal-agent problems, and commons games, among others.

 

  • Jörn P. W. Scharlemann, Department of Zoology, University of Oxford, South Parks Road, Oxford OX1 3PS, UK
  • Catherine C. Eckel, Department of Economics (0316), Virginia Polytechnic Institute and State University, Blacksburg, VA 24061, USA
  • Alex Kacelnika, Department of Political Science, Rice University, Houston, TX 77251-1892, USA
  • Rick K. Wilson,

Scharlemann Jörn P. W., Catherine C. Eckel, Alex Kacelnika, Rick K. Wilson [2001], "The value of a smile: Game theory with a human face", Journal of Economic Psychology, Volume 22, Issue 5, October 2001, Pages 617-640.

Many economists and biologists view cooperation as anomalous: animals (including humans) that pursue their own self-interest have superior survival odds to their altruistic or cooperative neighbors. However, in many situations there are substantial gains to the group that can achieve cooperation among its members, and to individuals who are members of those groups. For an individual, the key to successful cooperation is the ability to identify cooperative partners. The ability to signal and detect the intention to cooperate would be a very valuable skill for humans to posses.

Smiling is frequently observed in social interactions between humans, and may be used as a signal of the intention to cooperate. However, given that humans have the ability to smile falsely, the ability to detect intentions may go far beyond the ability to recognize a smile. In the present study, we examine the value of a smile in a simple bargaining context. 120 subjects participate in a laboratory experiment consisting of a simple two-person, one-shot "trust" game with monetary payoffs. Each subject is shown a photograph of his partner prior to the game; the photograph is taken from a collection that includes one smiling and one non-smiling image for each of 60 individuals. These photographs are also rated by a separate set of subjects who complete a semantic differential survey on affective and behavioral interpretations of the images.

Results lend some support to the prediction that smiles can elicit cooperation among strangers in a one-shot interaction. Other characteristics of faces also appear to elicit cooperation. Factor analysis of the survey data reveals an important factor, termed "cooperation", which is strongly related to trusting behavior in the game. This factor is correlated with smiling, but is somewhat more strongly predictive of behavior than a smile alone. In addition, males are found to be more cooperative, especially towards female images, whereas females are least cooperative towards female images. Author Keywords: Trust; Behavioral game theory; Facial expressions; Sex differences Psychological classification codes: 3040; 2360JEL classification codes: C7; C91

 

Volker Grossmann : Socioeconomic Institute, University of Zurich, R€amisstrasse 62, CH-8001 Zurich, Switzerland

Grossmann Volker [2002], "Is it rational to internalize the personal norm that one should reciprocate?", Journal of Economic Psychology, Volume 23, Issue 1 (Feb-2002)

This paper shows in a simple game-theoretic model that it can be rational for non-altruistic individuals to adopt a personal value-based norm to reciprocate. Moreover, it is argued that such a behavioral commitment is feasible and thus self-binding. Reciprocal behavior has become a stylized fact in experimental labor markets. Our analysis suggests that in laboratory experiments ‘‘workers’’ may provide high effort either because they adopted the norm to behave reciprocally fair or because they fear to ‘‘work’’ with an ‘‘employer’’ who adopted the norm to punish unkind behavior. JEL classiffication: C70 Keywords: Reciprocal behavior; Personal norms; Experimental labor market; Fair wage-effort hypothesis

 

  • Anna Gunnthorsdottir: Department of Management and Policy, University of Arizona
  • Kevin McCabe: Economic Science Laboratory, University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ, USA
  • Vernon Smith Economic Science Laboratory, University of Arizona, Tucson, AZ, USA

Gunnthorsdottir A., K. McCabe, V. Smith [2002], "Using the Machiavellianism instrument to predict trustworthiness in a bargaining game", Journal of Economic Psychology, Volume 23, Issue 1 (Feb-2002)

Game-theoretic experiments have revealed substantial individual differences where the game allows for off-equilibrium behavior such as trust and reciprocity. We explore the personality psychology and decision making literatures and conclude that these individual differences are likely to be mediated by differential emotional arousal. We argue that Christie and Geis’s Machiavellianism scale (Mach-IV) is an instrument that allows the identification of types who vary in cooperativeness. We use that test to predict the behavior of participants in a two-person one-shot constituent game in which subjects face a choice between trust and distrust, and between reciprocation (trustworthiness) and defection. We find that the Mach-IV scale does not predict trusting behavior. It does, however, predict reciprocity. Over one half of those who score low to average on the scale reciprocate trust. High scorers overwhelmingly defect when it is to their advantage to do so. PsycINFO classiffication: 3020; 3120 JEL classiffication: C72 Keywords: Game; Machiavellianism; Reciprocity; Trust

 

Miriam Tatzel: Empire State College, State University of New York, 240 North Main Street, New City, NY 10956, USA

Tatzel Miriam [2002], "'Money worlds' and well-being: An integration of money dispositions, materialism and price-related behavior", Journal of Economic Psychology, Volume 23, Issue 1 (Feb-2002)

Psychological aspects of money attitudes, material values, and spending are brought together in an integrated model of consumption patterns. Tightness with money combined with high materialism predicts value-seeking bargain hunting; looseness with money combined with high materialism predicts price-seeking conspicuous spending; tightness with money combined with low materialism predicts price aversion and reluctance to spend; and looseness with money combined with low materialism predicts spending on experiences rather than things. Being overly tight with money, overly loose, materialistic, or overly concerned with financial success are all associated with lowered well-being. Author Keywords: Consumer psychology; Lifestyle; Materialism; Money; Well-being JEL classification codes: D1

 

Andreoni, James, [1995], “Cooperation in Public-Goods Experiments: Kindness or Confusion,” American Economic Review 85: 891- 904.

 

Martin Sefton, Robert Shupp and James Walker [2000], "The Effects of Rewards and Sanctions in Provision of Public Goods", working paper,  July, 2000. http://www.nottingham.ac.uk/ economics/cedex/papers/index.html#work

We examine how opportunities to reward and sanction other group members affect resource allocations in a voluntary contribution mechanism experiment. Rewards represent a zero sum transfer from participants giving to those receiving rewards. Sanctions represent a net loss, a cost to both the participant giving and the participant receiving the sanction. In our baseline treatment, without opportunities to reward or sanction, we reproduce the results of other studies: group allocations to the public good are less than fully efficient and decline with repetition. When we allow participants to reward other group members after observing allocation decisions, group allocations temporarily increase before falling to the same level as in the baseline. With opportunities to sanction, group allocations are stable and higher than in the baseline. The highest group allocations are observed in a treatment in which participants can use sanctions as well as rewards. Initially, earnings exceed those in the baseline when subjects have opportunities to reward, or opportunities to use both rewards and sanctions; earnings are below the baseline when participants have an opportunity to sanction, but not reward. Over the course of multiple decision rounds, however, earnings in the four treatments tend to converge. By the last round, the earnings difference between the four treatments is minimal. JEL Classifications: C92

 

  • Kyung Hwan Baik : Department of Economics, Sungkyunkwan University, Seoul 110-745, South Korea
  • In-Gyu Kim : Hallym Academy of Sciences and Department of Economics, Hallym University, Chunchon 200-702, South Korea
  • Sunghyun Na : Graduate student, Department of Economics, Pennsylvania State University, University Park, PA 16802, USA

Kyung Hwan Baik, In-Gyu Kim, Sunghyun Na [2001], "Bidding for a group-specific public-good prize", Journal of Public Economics, Volume 82, Issue 3, December 2001, Pages 415-429.

We examine the equilibrium effort levels of individual players and groups in a context in which two groups compete with each other to win a group-specific public-good prize, the players choose their effort levels simultaneously and independently, and the winning group is determined by the selection rule of all-pay auctions. We first prove nonexistence of a pure-strategy Nash equilibrium, and then construct a mixed-strategy Nash equilibrium. At the Nash equilibrium, the only active player in each group is a player whose valuation for the prize is the highest in that group; all the other players expend zero effort; and the equilibrium effort levels depend solely on two values: the highest valuation for the prize in each group. Author Keywords: Public-good prize; Contest; All-pay auction; Private provision of public goods JEL classification codes: D71; D72; D44; H41

 

Haag Matthew, Lagunoff Roger [2000], Social Norms, Local Interaction, and Neighborhood Planning, Working Pper, July 11, 2000

http://www.courses.fas.harvard.edu/~ec2052/syllabus/ExtendedReadings/

This paper examines optimal social linkage when each individual's repeated interaction with each of his neighbors creates spillovers. Each individuals' discount factor is randomly determined. A planner chooses a local interaction network or neighborhood design before the discount factors are realized. Each individual then plays a repeated Prisoner's Dilemma game with his neighbors. A local trigger strategy equilibrium (LTSE) describes an equilibrium in which each individual conditions his cooperation on the cooperation of at least one \acceptable" group of neighbors. Our main results demonstrate a basic tradeoff in the design problem between suboptimal punishment and social con°ict. Potentially suboptimal punishment arises in designs with local interactions since in this case monitoring is imperfect. Due to heterogeneity of discount factors, however, greater social conflict may arise in more connected networks. When residents' discount factors are known to the planner, the optimal design exhibits a cooperative "core" and an uncooperative "fringe." Uncooperative (impatient) types are connected to cooperative ones who tolerate their free riding so that social conflict is kept to a minimum. By contrast, when residents' discount factors are iid, the optimal design partitions individuals into maximally connected cliques (e.g., cul-de-sacs). Optimal clique size increases the more patient an individual is likely to be. Finally, if types are correlated, then incomplete graphs with small overlap (e.g., grids) are possible. JEL Fields: C7, D62, D7. Keywords: repeated games, local interaction, social norms, neighborhood design, local trigger strategy, spatial design.

 

Möbius Markus M [2000], The Formation of Ghettos as a Local Interaction Phenomenon, Working Paper, MIT April 14, 2000

I analyze a simple evolutionary model of residential segregation based on decentralized racism which extends Schelling's (1972) well-known tipping model by allowing for local interaction between residents. The richer set-up explains not only the persistence of ghettos, but also provides a mechanism for the rapid transition from an all-white to an all-black equilibrium. On one-dimensional streets segregation arises once a group becomes sufficiently dominant in the housing market. However, the resulting ghettos are not persistent, and periodic shifts in the market can give rise to "avenue waves". On two-dimensional inner-cities, on the other hand, ghettos can be persistent due to the \encircling phenomenon" if the majority ethnic group is sufficiently less tolerant than the minority. I review the history of residential segregation in the US and argue that my model can explain the rapid rise of almost exclusively black ghettos at the beginning of the 20th century. For the analysis of my model I introduce a new technique to characterize the medium and long-run stochastic dynamics. I show that clustering predicts the behavior of large-scale processes with many agents more accurately than standard stochastic stability analysis, because the latter concept overemphasizes the 'noisy' part of the stochastic dynamics.

 

Kandori Michihiroy [2001], "Introduction to Repeated Games with Private Monitoring", Working Paper, Faculty of Economics, University of Tokyo

We present a brief overview of recent developments on discounted repeated games with (imperfect) private monitoring. The literature explores the possibility of cooperation in a long-term relationship, where each agent receives imperfect private information about the opponents’ actions. Although this class of games admits a wide range of applications such as collusion under secret price-cutting, exchange of goods with uncertain quality, and observation errors, it has fairly complex mathematical structure due to the lack of common information shared by players. This is in sharp contrast to the well-explored case of repeated games under public information (with the celebrated Folk Theorems), and until recently little had been known about the private monitoring case. However, rapid developments in the past few years have revealed the possibility of cooperation under private monitoring for some class of games.

 

Ely Jeffrey [1996], "Local Conventions", Working Paper, Department of Economics, Northwestern University

It is shown that player mobility has important consequences for the long-run equilibrium distribution in dynamic evolutionary models of strategy adjustment, when updating is prone to small probability perturbations, i.e. "mistakes" or "mutations." Ellison (1993) concluded that the effect on the matching process of localized "neighborhoods" was to strengthen the stability of risk-dominant outcomes, originally demonstrated by Kandori, Mailath, and Rob (1993) and Young (1993). I consider a model in which players can choose the neighborhoods to which they belong. When strategies and locations are updated simultaneously, only efficient strategies survive and risk-dominance plays no special role. The robustness of this conclusion is emphasized in a general locational model in which strategy revision opportunities are allowed to arrive at a faster rate than opportunities to change locations. The efficient strategy persists in all cases in which the locational structure is non-trivial. Moreover, even as revision rates become arbitrarily larger than mobility rates, the efficient strategy occurs with boundedly positive relative frequency. This demonstrates that the fixed location models of KMR, Young, and Ellison are not close approximations when players have any degree of mobility, however limited.

 


Community governance

Bowles S., Gintis H. [2000], "Social Capital and Community Governance", Santa Fe Institute Working Papers, http://www.santafe.edu/sfi/publications/01wplist.html

Social capital generally refers to trust, concern for ones associates, a willingness to live by the norms of one’s community and to punish those who do not. While essential to good governance, these behaviors and dispositions appear to conflict with the fundamental behavioral assumptions of economics whose archetypal individual—Homo economicus—is entirely self-regarding. We regard these behaviors and dispositions as aspects of what we term community governance. We suggest that (i) community governance addresses some common market and state failures but typically relies on insider-outsider distinctions that may be morally repugnant; (ii) the individual motivations supporting community governance are not captured by either the conventional self-interested preferences of Homo economicus or by unconditional altruism towards one’s fellow community members; (iii) well-designed institutions make communities, markets and states complements, not substitutes; (iv) with poorly designed institutions, markets and states can crowd out community governance; (v) some distributions of property rights are better than others at fostering community governance and assuring complementarity among communities, states and markets; and (vi) far from representing holdovers from a premodern era, the small scale local interactions that characterize communities are likely to increase in importance as the economic problems that community governance handles relatively well become more important. 

 

Henrich Joseph, Boyd Robert, Bowles Samuel, Camerer Colin, Fehr Ernst, Gintis Herbert, McElreath Richard. [2001], "In Search of Homo Economicus: Behavioral Experiments in 15 Small-Scale Societies", American Economic Review, Vol. 91, No. 2, May 2001, pp.73-78.
http://webuser.bus.umich.edu/henrich/

Henrich J., Boyd R., Bowles S., Camerer C., Fehr E., Gintis H., McElreath R. [2001], "Cooperation, Reciprocity and Punishment in Fifteen Small-scale Societies", Santa Fe Institute Working Paper, http://www.santafe.edu/sfi/publications/01wplist.html

Recent investigations have uncovered large, consistent deviations from the predictions of the textbook representation of Homo Economicus: in addition to their own material payoffs, many experimental subjects appear to care about fairness and reciprocity and reward those who act in a cooperative manner while punishing those who do not even when these actions are costly to the individual. These deviations from what we will term the canonical Economic Man model have important consequences for a wide range of economic phenomena, including the optimal design of institutions and contracts, the allocation of property rights, the conditions for successful collective action, the analysis of incomplete contracts, and the persistence of noncompetitive wage premia. However, existing research is limited because virtually all subjects have been university students: we would like to know how universal these behaviors are and whether they vary with local cultural or economic environments. To address these questions we and our collaborators (11 anthropologists and 1 economist) conducted ultimatum, public good, and dictator game experiments with subjects from fifteen hunter gatherer, nomadic herding and other small-scale societies exhibiting a wide variety of economic and cultural conditions. We can summarize our results as follows. First, the Economic Man model is not supported in any society studied. Second, there is considerably more behavioral variability across groups than had been found in previous cross-cultural research and the canonical model fails in a wider variety of ways than in previous experiments. Third, group-level differences in the structure of everyday social interactions explain a substantial portion of the behavioral variation across societies: the higher the degree of market integration and the higher the payoffs to cooperation in the production of their livelihood, the greater the level of cooperation in experimental games. Fourth, individual-level economic and demographic variables do not explain behavior either within or across groups. Fifth, behavior in the experiments is generally consistent with economic patterns of everyday life in these societies.

 

Gintis Herbert [2001], "The Hitchhiker's Guide to Altruism: Gene-Culture Coevolution and the Internalization of Norms", Working Paper,

http://www-unix.oit.umass.edu/~gintis/

The internalization of norms refers to the tendency of human beings to adopt social norms through the teaching of parents (vertical transmission) or influential elders (oblique transmission). Authority rather than fitness-enhancing capacity accounts for the adoption of internalized norms. Suppose there is one genetic locus that controls whether or not an individual is capable of internalizing norms. We extend the seminal models of Cavalli-Sforza and Feldman (1981) to show that if adopting a norm is fitness enhancing, the allele for internalization can evolve to fixation. Moreover, even a small amount of biased vertical transmission or oblique transmission renders fixation virtually inevitable. This is Baldwin-like effect, because the gene for internalization, which facilitates learning the fitness-enhancing trait, is incorporated into the genome. We then add to the model a replicator dynamic (horizontal transmission of fitness-enhancing phenotypic traits), showing that the tendency of agents to switch from lower to higher-fitness norms enlarges the basin of attraction of the internalization allele. Finally, we use this framework to model analytically Herbert Simon's (1990) explanation of altruism. Simon suggested that altruistic norms, which are by definition fitness-reducing, could `hitchhike' on the general tendency of the internalization of norms to be fitness-enhancing. We find that the altruistic phenotype can evolve only if there is a sufficient level of oblique transmission, even when there is a strong horizontal transmission process biased against the altruistic norm.

 

Bowles Samuel, Gintis H. [2001], "Walrasian Economics in Retrospect", Working Paper

Two basic tenets of the Walrasian model, behavior based on self-interested exogenous preferences and complete and costless contracting have recently come under critical scrutiny. First, social norms and psychological dispositions extending beyond the selfish motives of Homo economicus may have an important bearing on outcomes, even in competitive markets. Second, market outcomes depend on strategic interactions in which power in the political sense is exercised. It follows that economics must become more psychological and more institutional, yet no less no less dedicated to the construction of mathematical general economic equilibrium models.

Bowles Samuel, Gintis H. [1998], The Moral Economy of Communities: Structured Populations and the Evolution of Prosocial Norms, Evolution & Human Behavior

http://www-unix.oit.umass.edu/~gintis/

We model three mechanisms by which communities raise the net benefits to individual pro-social behaviors: reputation, retaliation and segmentation. Unlike most treatments of the evolution of group-beneficial traits our communities promote pro-social behaviors independently of any process of group selection. We further show that the restricted mobility associated with communities (parochialism) enhances these mechanisms. Communities may thus be considered to be surrogates for a system of efficiency enhancing property and liability rights specifically adapted to informational settings that make formal property rights systems untenable and preclude the efficient centralized determination of outcomes. In short, communities persist because they solve problems that markets and governments cannot solve.

 

Bowles S., Boyd R., Fehr E., Gintis H. [1997], "Homo Reciprocans: A Research Initiative on the Origins, Dimensions, and Policy Implications of Reciprocal Fairness", Working Paper

http://www-unix.oit.umass.edu/~gintis/

Experimental economists and other social scientists have discovered an important form of human behavior that has been inadequately analyzed by behavioral scientists. In public goods, ultimatum, and other games where players gain from cooperative behavior, agents have a predisposition to cooperate and to undertake costly punishment of defectors, even when this behavior cannot be justified in terms of traditional game-theoretic equilibrium and learning concepts, even where interactions are long-lived and discount rates are low. We call this 'reciprocal fairness.' This research initiative has four research goals. First, can the experiments on reciprocal fairness be replicated with diverse subject pools and various strategic settings? Second, how might such behavior have evolved, given that it is formally altruistic, and hence `unfit' except under stringent circumstances? Third, how does the existence of reciprocal fairness influence our analysis of social policy in such areas as taxation, charity, redistributive expenditure, and criminal sentencing? Fourth, how to what extent does cultural variation induce differences in the strength of reciprocal behavior and conditions under which agents exhibit reciprocal fairness?

 

Fehr Ernst and Peter K. Zych [1998], "Intertemporal Choice under Habit Formation", Handbook of Experimental Economic Results, http://www.iew.unizh.ch/home/fehr/

Many of the most important choices in people’s lives have an inter-temporal dimension, i.e., these choices are associated with a flow of benefits or costs that accrue in the future. In addition, such choices are frequently habit-forming. Yet, little is known about habit forming inter-temporal choice behavior. This paper reports the results of an inter-temporal choice experiment with habit-formation. Subjects’ choices deviate systematically from individually optimal decisions in the direction of over-consumption. This over-consumption is partly driven by loss avoidance, comparable to a real life situation in which addicted people consume addictive substances only in order to overpower withdrawal symptoms. Our results thus reject the theory of rational addiction.

 

Gintis H. [2002], "Solving The Puzzle of Prosociality", Rationality and Society (forthcoming)

http://www-unix.oit.umass.edu/~gintis/

Abstract : Homo sapiens is the only species in which we observe extensive cooperation among large numbers of genetically unrelated individuals. Incompatible approaches to explaining cooperation among humans have been offered by sociologists, biologists, and economists. None is wholly successful. Each discipline, moreover, has ignored basic insights of the others. This paper explains cooperation by combining central contributions of these disciplines, developing a game-theoretic model of cultural evolution in which we use (a) the sociological concept of the internalization of norms to explain cultural transmission; (b) the biological concepts of vertical and oblique transmission to model the interaction of cultural and biological adaptation; and (c) opimization subject to constrations (rational action) and the replicator dynamic (imitation of successful behavior) to model the interaction between self-interested and altruistic behavior.

Gintis Herbert : The Puzzle of Prosociality

http://ideas.repec.org/p/wop/safiwp/01-10-059.html

How is cooperation among large numbers of unrelated individuals sustained? Cooperation generally requires altruism, where individuals take actions that are group-beneficial but personally costly. Why do selfish agents not drive out altruistic behavior? This is the puzzle of prosociality. Altruism is supported by culture. Sociology treats culture as a set of norms that are transmitted by socialization institutions and internalized by individuals. Altruism, in this approach, is thus sustained by the internalization of norms. Biology treats culture as knowledge that is passed to children from parents (vertical transmission), from other prominent adults (oblique transmission), and from peers (horizontal transmission), such that individuals with higher payoffs have a higher level of biological fitness, leading norms to follow a dynamic of Darwinian selection. Altruism, in this approach, can be sustained only if group selection is feasible, which it rarely is. Economics uses evolutionary game theory to model culture as strategies deployed in social interaction that evolve according to a replicator dynamic, in which individuals shift from lower to higher payoff norms. In this approach, altruism cannot be sustained, but cooperation is possible with repeated interactions and a sufficiently low discount rate. This paper integrates these approaches and shows that altruism, as well as norms that reduce both individual and group payoffs, can be supported in a stable equilibrium.

 

Rajiv Sethi Department of Economics, Barnard College, Columbia University, 3009 Broadway, New York NY 10027

Sethi R., Somanathan E. [2002], “What can we learn from cultural group selection and co-evolutionary models?”, Working Paper.

Economists have long operated on the assumption that the hypothesis of material selfinterest is an adequate approximation to human motivation in economic decision-making. This hypothesis has recently come under fierce challenge from experimentalists, who have documented robust and systematic departures from self-interest in controlled laboratory settings (see, for instance, Fehr and Gächter, 2000). Rejection of self-interest as a governing hypothesis does not, however, entail an embrace of altruism. Experimental subjects tend to care about fairness and efficiency as well as their own self-interest, but also reveal a strong propensity to reward generosity and punish opportunism on the part of others. Such preferences for reciprocity can indeed result in greater efficiency in some environments, but can also reduce efficiency in others. For instance, reciprocity tends to raise aggregate payoffs in public goods games with punishment, while it lowers aggregate payoffs in ultimatum games. It is not pro-sociality with which humans are endowed, but rather a predilection for reciprocity which, given the right context, can have pro-social effects. It is the predilection itself, rather than its consequences in particular environments, that evolutionary models should account for. An important feature that distinguishes preferences for reciprocity from altruistic preferences is the fact that under rather general conditions, the presence of people with such preferences, if observable, can induce opportunistic individuals to act pro-socially. They do so at some cost to themselves, but avoid the greater cost of being punished. The fact that the presence of reciprocators in a group induces all group members to act pro-socially can allow preferences for reciprocity to survive and spread in competition with self-interested preferences even in the absence of assortative interaction.  

 

Fehr E., Gächter S.  [2000], “Fairness and Retaliation: The Economics of Reciprocity”, Journal of Economic Perspectives 14: 159-181.

Fehr E., Schmidt K. [2000], “Fairness, Incentives and Contractual Choices”, European Economic Review 44: 1057-1068.

Gintis H. [2000]. “Strong Reciprocity and Human Sociality”, Journal of Theoretical Biology, 206: 169-179.

Guttman J.M. [2002], “Repeated Interaction and the Evolution of Preferences for Reciprocity”, Economic Journal, forthcoming.

Richerson P.J., Boyd R. [1999], “Complex Societies: The Evolutionary Origins of a Crude Superorganism”, Human Nature, 10(3): 253-89.

Rubin P.H., Somanathan E. [1998], “Humans as factors of production: an evolutionary analysis”, Managerial and Decision Economics 19: 441—455.

Sethi R., Somanathan E. [2001], “Norm Compliance and Strong Reciprocity”, Santa Fe Institute Working Paper 01-09-048.

Sethi R., Somanathan E. [2001], “Preference Evolution and Reciprocity”, Journal of Economic Theory 97: 273—297.

 

Sethi R., Somanathan E. [2001], “Norm Compliance and Strong Reciprocity”, Santa Fe Institute Working Paper 01-09-048.

Abstract : Strong reciprocity refers to the willingness to sacrifice one’s own material selfinterest to punish others for opportunistic actions. This propensity provides a decentralized mechanism for the enforcement of social norms, but its extent and persistence poses a theoretical puzzle. Since opportunistic individuals choose optimally to comply with or violate norms based on the likelihood and severity of sanctioning they anticipate, such individuals will always outperform reciprocators within any group. The presence of reciprocators in a group can, however, alter the behavior of opportunists in such a manner as to benefit all members of the group (including reciprocators). We show that under these circumstances, reciprocators can invade a population of opportunists when groups dissolve and are formed anew according to a process of purely random (non-assortative) matching. Furthermore, even when these conditions are not satisfied (so that an opportunistic population is stable) there may exist additional stable population states in which reciprocators are present.

Sethi R., Somanathan E. [2002], “Understanding Reciprocity”, Forthcoming: Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization

Abstract : This paper surveys the evolutionary game theoretic literature on reciprocity in human interactions, dealing both with long-term relationships and with sporadic interactions. Four basic themes, repetition, commitment, assortation, and parochialism, appear repeatedly throughout the literature. Repetition can give rise to the evolution of behavior that exhibits reciprocity-like features but a vast array of other behaviors are also stable. In sporadic interactions, reciprocity can be stable if the propensity to punish selfish actions can induce opportunists to cooperate, if reciprocators themselves behave opportunistically when they expect others to do so, or if matching is sufficiently assortative. JEL Classification: C72, D62. Keywords: Reciprocity, Evolution, Assortation, Commitment, Parochialism.

 

Axelrod R., Hamilton W.D., [1981], "The evolution of cooperation", Science, 211, 1390-1396.

Axelrod R., [1984], The evolution of cooperation, Basic Books, New York

Axelrod R. [1986], "An evolutionary approach to norms", American Political Science Review, 80, 1095-111.

 

James C. Cox

Cox J.C. [2000], Implications of Game Triads for Observations of Trust and Reciprocity, Working Paper.

Abstract: This paper develops a triadic design for conducting trust and reciprocity experiments. A large literature on single-game trust and reciprocity experiments is based on the assumption that subjects utility payoffs are the same as their own monetary payoffs in the experiments. Such designs test compound hypotheses that include the hypothesis that other-regarding preferences do not affect behavior. In contrast, experiments with the triadic design do discriminate between transfers resulting from trust or reciprocity and transfers resulting from other-regarding preferences. Decomposing trust from altruism and reciprocity from altruism is critical to obtaining empirical information that can guide the process of constructing models that can increase the empirical validity of game theory.

cf. le jeu d'investissement de Berg, Dickhaut and McCabe (1995) : Joyce Berg, John Dickhaut, Kevin McCabeBerg J., Dickhaut J., McCabe K. [1995], "Trust, Reciprocity, and Social History", Games and Economic Behavior, July 95, 10(1), p.122-42.

 

Richerson P.J. and R. Boyd [1998], "The Evolution of Human Ultra-Sociality", In: Ideology, Warfare, and Indoctrinability, I. Eibl-Eibisfeldt and F. Salter, eds. pp. 71–95, Berghan Books, 1998

http://www.sscnet.ucla.edu/anthro/faculty/boyd/Publications.htm

 

Henrich J. and R. Boyd [1998], "The Evolution of Conformist Transmission and the Emergence of Between-Group Differences", Evolution and Human Behavior, 19: 215–242. 1998.

http://www.sscnet.ucla.edu/anthro/faculty/boyd/Publications.htm

Unlike other animal species, much of the variation among human groups is cultural: genetically similar people living in similar environments exhibit strikingly different patterns of behavior because they have different, culturally acquired beliefs and values. Such cultural transmission is based on complex, derived psychological mechanisms that are likely to have been shaped by natural selection. It is important to understand the nature of these evolved psychological mechanisms because they determine which beliefs and values spread and persist in human groups. Boyd and Richerson (1985) showed that a tendency to acquire the most common behavior exhibited in a society was adaptive in a simple model of evolution in a spatially varying environment because such a tendency increases the probability of acquiring adaptive beliefs and values. Here, we study the evolution of such "conformist transmission" in a more general model in which environments vary in both time and space. The analysis of this model indicates that conformist transmission is favored under a very broad range of conditions, broader in fact than the range of conditions that favor a substantial reliance on social learning. The analysis also suggests that there is a synergistic relationship between the evolution of imitation and the evolution of conformism. We conclude by examining the role of conformism in explaining the maintenance of cultural differences among groups.

 

Richerson P.J. and R. Boyd [1999], The Evolutionary Dynamics of a Crude Super Organism, Human Nature, 10: 253–289, 1999.

http://www.sscnet.ucla.edu/anthro/faculty/boyd/Publications.htm

The complexity of human societies of the past few thousand years rivals that of social insect societies. We hypothesize that two sets of social “instincts” underpin and constrain the evolution of complex societies. One set is ancient and shared with other social primate species, and one is derived and unique to our lineage. The latter evolved by the late Pleistocene, and led to the evolution of institutions of intermediate complexity in acephalous societies. The institutions of complex societies often conflict with our social instincts. The complex societies of the last few thousand years can function only because cultural evolution has created effective “work-arounds” to manage such instincts. We describe a series of work-arounds and use the data on the relative effectiveness of WWII armies to test the work-around hypothesis. Keywords: Gene-culture coevolution, complex societies, conflict, cooperation

 

Samuel Bowles S., Gintis H. [2002], "The Origins of Human Cooperation", Working Paper, Santa Fe Institute.

http://www.santafe.edu/sfi/publications/wpabstract/200208035

Abstract: Biological explanations of cooperation are based on kin altruism, reciprocal altruism, and mutualism, all of which apply to human and nonhuman species alike. But human cooperation is based in part on capacities that are unique to, or at least much more highly developed in, "Homo sapiens.” We seek an explanation of cooperation that works for humans, but does not work for other species, or works substantially less well. Central to our explanation will be human cognitive, linguistic, and physical capacities that allow the formulation of general norms of social conduct, the emergence of social institutions regulating this conduct, the psychological capacity to internalize norms, and the basing of group membership on such non-kin characteristics as ethnicity and linguistic behavior, which facilitate highly costly conflicts among groups. We show that these could have coevolved with other human traits in a plausible representation of the relevant environments. The forms of cooperation we seek to explain are confirmed by natural observation, historical accounts, and behavioral experiments. Our account is based on a plausible evolutionary dynamic involving some combination of genetic and cultural elements, the consistency of which can be demonstrated through formal modeling. Moreover, the workings of the models we develop account for human cooperation under parameter values consistent with what can be reasonably inferred about the environments in which humans have lived. Keywords: game theory, emotions and decision making, socialization, multilevel selection, costly signaling, models of cooperation in humans

 

Samuel Bowles S., Gintis H. [2002], " Prosocial Emotions ", Working Paper, Santa Fe Institute.

http://www.santafe.edu/sfi/publications/wpabstract/200207028

Abstract: Adherence to social norms is underwritten not only by the cognitively mediated pursuit of self-interest, but also by emotions. Shame, guilt, pride, regret, joy, and other visceral reactions play a central role in sustaining cooperative relations, including successful transactions in the absence of complete contracting. Prosocial emotions function like the basic emotion, “pain,” in providing guides for action that bypass the explicit cognitive optimizing process that lies at the core of the standard behavioral model in economics. We consider a public goods game where agents maximize a utility function that captures five distinct motives: personal material payoffs, one's valuation of the payoffs to others, which depend both on one's altruism and one's degree of reciprocity, and one's sense of guilt or shame in response to one's own and others' actions. We present empirical evidence suggesting that such emotions play a role in the public goods game, and we develop an analytical model and an agent-based simulation showing that reciprocity, shame, and guilt increase the level of cooperation in the group. Finally, we provide an explanation of the long-term evolutionary success of prosocial emotions in terms of both the individual- and group-level benefits they confer. Keywords: game theory, emotions, decision making, models of cooperation in humans

 

http://www.sscnet.ucla.edu/soc/faculty/kollock/

Kollock Peter [1994], "The Emergence of Exchange Structures: An Experimental Study of Uncertainty, Commitment, and Trust", American Journal of Sociology 100(2):313-345.

Kollock Peter [1998a], "Social Dilemmas: The Anatomy of Cooperation", Annual Review of Sociology 24:183-214.

Kollock Peter [1998b], "The Economies of Online Cooperation: Gifts and Public Goods in Computer Communities", in Communities in Cyberspace, edited by Marc Smith and Peter Kollock. London: Routledge.

Kollock Peter [1998c], "The Production of Trust in Online Markets", Working paper, UCLA, final version to appear in Advances in Group Processes (Vol. 16), edited by E. J. Lawler, M. Macy, S. Thyne, and H. A. Walker Greenwich, CT: JAI Press. 1999.

Authors: Stefano Battiston, Eric Bonabeau, Gerard Weisbuch

Battiston S., Bonabeau E., Weisbuch G. [2002], "Decision making dynamics in corporate boards", Working Paper.

Abstract : Members of boards of directors of large corporations who also serve together on an outside board, form the so called interlock graph of the board and are assumed to have a strong influence on each others' opinion. We here study how the size and the topology of the interlock graph affect the probability that the board approves a strategy proposed by the Chief Executive Officer. We propose a measure of the impact of the interlock on the decision making, which is found to be a good predictor of the decision dynamics outcome. We present two models of decision making dynamics, and we apply them to the data of the boards of the largest US corporations in 1999.

 


Gift and keeping while giving

 

Maurice Godelier

Godelier M. [1996], L'énigme du don, Fayard, Paris (1996).

Marcel Mauss

Mauss M. [1925], "Essai sur le don. Forme et raison de l’échange dans les sociétés primitives", Les PUF, Paris, 1968. Coll. Bibliothèque de sociologie contemporaine, publication originale : l'Année Sociologique, 1, 1925.

http://www.uqac.uquebec.ca/zone30/Classiques_des_sciences_sociales/index.html

Annette Weiner

Weiner A. [1992], Inalienable Possessions: The Paradox of Keeping-while-Giving, Berkeley, University of California Press, 1992

Bronislaw Malinowski

Malinowski B. [1921], "The Primitive Economy of the Trobriand Islanders", Economic Journal, Vol.31, N°121, mars 1921

Jerry and Edmund Leach

Leach J. and E. [1983], The Kula: New Perspectives on Massim Exchange, Cambridge University Press, 1983.

Kula entre les îles Trobriand, Woodlark, Gawa, Vakuta, Kitawa, Normanby, Tubetube, Louisiade, Rossel Island

Objets précieux (kitomu) servant au kula (mais servant aussi à d'autres usages, comme monnaie sauf dans certaines îles comme Kiriwina, où ils ne servent qu'au kula): bracelets (mwali) et colliers (soulava).

Ces objets initient des relations, en particulier des relations matrimoniales (île Woodlark). Ils servent aux échanges cérémoniels (après le décès d'un homme).

Route du kula : le bracelet est donné (en tant qu'objet kula), il passe de main en main jusqu'à ce qu'il parvienne dans celle de quelqu'un qui possède un collier de rang équivalent. Il fait l'échange et le collier voyage en sens inverse jusqu'à revenir après plusieurs mois ou années à l'émetteur. Le périple du kula est achevé et le collier peut sortir du cycle kula. Aux deux bouts de la chaîne, il y a propriété, les autres ont les objets à titre de prêt (don devant être compensé plus tard par un contre-don).

Que gagne l'émetteur ? Annette Weiner (pas l'objet kula, de même valeur) mais la renommé et des cadeaux ou dons que lui valent son habileté à négocier (les relations commerciales qu'il a ainsi initiées et qui sont le canal d'échanges commerciaux).

 

 

Terence C. Burnham,  Harvard Business School, Harvard University, 950 Massachusetts Avenue 313, Cambridge, MA 02139, USA

Burnham T.C. [2003], "Engineering altruism: a theoretical and experimental investigation of anonymity and gift giving", Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, Volume 50, Issue 1, January 2003, Pages 133-144.

Abstract : Three double blind treatments of a US$ 10 dictator game are used to examine the role of anonymity and perceptions of anonymity in pro-social behavior. One treatment has dictators viewing pictures of recipients, the second has recipients receiving pictures of dictators and the third is a pictureless control. In each treatment, more than 50 percent of dictators give US$ 0. For those dictators who give positive amounts, the modal gift is US$ 5 in each photograph treatment versus US$ 2 in the control. Twenty-five percent of subjects in each photograph treatment give at least US$ 5 versus 4 percent of subjects in the control. Author Keywords: Dictator game; Fairness; Anonymity; Framing JEL classification codes: A13; C72; C91